Before the super-apps of today, there were banks. They provided a number of services under one roof, including payment, clearing, verification of third-parties, stores of value, and credit. To borrow a phrase from the product world, banks handled a number of “jobs to be done”. But at their core, banks were, and still are, simply trusted brokers of data and information.
Over centuries in that role, banks created a number of products and services, and the resulting economies of scale, as well as ensuing regulation, emerged as competitive moats. But the rise of computational power and interconnectivity allows for close-to-zero marginal cost of processing information and distribution, and cheap capital finances such experiments at scale. The result is that banks can now be “unbundled”.
This is the first in a series of two articles on the potential for new digital players to disrupt Pakistan’s banking and broader financial system. Today’s piece focuses on credit and deposit products.
Deposits are the ultimate moat
Credit products are commodities. For most businesses, what matters most is the price and speed at which they can access credit. As costs of distribution (defined by the cost of getting a financial product into the hands of a customer) trend to zero with digital financial infrastructure, and costs of processing decline sharply given the volume of data that can now be routed through algorithms to provide credit decisions, marginal costs are expected to decline rapidly. Since products are relatively undifferentiated, the only differentiation will remain in the cost of capital, which will become the ultimate moat.
Most digital financial companies start in high-yielding asset classes, such as buy-now-pay-later and salary-advances, but yields for those assets fall as the market matures and competition increases. These companies finance much of their lending by taking on debt. This might be sufficient to build a billion-dollar business if Pakistan had a large enough market for high-yield products and if companies could access large domestic debt markets. Neither is true.
Cheap deposits are the key for fintechs with credit products to ensure long-term competitiveness. Without access to deposit products, fintechs risk becoming small specialty lenders that may eventually get out-competed and out-priced by companies that can finance such products from a lower cost of capital.
Bank economics, and how digital banks will compete
So let’s crunch some numbers on deposits.1
The average amount in a deposit account at the end of 2020 was roughly PKR 280,000. That number has only been growing at 5 percent CAGR over the ten years prior, so it would be safe to assume that the average amount in a deposit account may be roughly PKR 300,000 right now, or roughly USD 1700. The weighted average rate on deposits was around 3.4 percent, and the weighted average lending rate was 8 percent. Let’s be generous to the bank and assume the deposit rate hasn’t changed much, but the lending rate is 10 percent. Finally let’s assume the bank keeps 15 percent as cash reserves and does not lend it out (this number is closer to 35 percent if one uses the money multiplier as an assumption). The bank can then expect to make USD 85 per “average” deposit account.2
In order to be profitable on unit basis, the aggregate costs of acquisition of both the depositor and the borrower have to be lower than that amount. I doubt that’s the case for a traditional Pakistani bank, which is why — and anyone who’s tried to open a retail deposit account can attest to this — most banks couldn’t care less about it. In fact, below a certain balance in a deposit account, it probably doesn’t make business sense for banks to service the customer without charging all manner of fees.
Incidentally, the average amount in a current account, which makes up two-thirds of all accounts, is only PKR around 150,000 or roughly USD 850. Using our earlier assumptions, this is around USD 43 of margin that may be used for all acquisition costs.
None of this should surprise anyone who has tried to access financial products in Pakistan and run into the frustrating tangle of paperwork, wet signatures and indifference. The existing physical infrastructure of banks and its associated manpower is simply too costly to provide financial services profitably to the majority of the population.
But that’s why digital financial companies have a real opportunity in Pakistan. Their costs of acquisition and distribution can be significantly lower, allowing them to access a greater segment of the population, both as depositors and borrowers, and to build a valuable business. However, digital financial services companies also risk either irrelevance or aggressive foreign expansion if they’re unable to roll out deposit products in Pakistan.
The Falling Money Multiplier
Let’s talk a bit about an interesting macroeconomy metric.
The money multiplier is a measure of how much money is created in response to each additional rupee created in bank reserves through central bank liquidity injections or foreign inflows. The multiplier effect happens because banks lend out a fraction of their deposits, and the money lent often ends up in another deposit account, a portion of which is lent out, and so forth.
Traditionally, the multiplier is a function of reserve requirements, i.e., the amount that the State Bank instructs the banks to keep on hand and not lend.
Now, the money multiplier has fallen since its peak of around 3.7 at the end of 2014 to 2.8 in the last SBP monetary policy report. That’s a 24 percent reduction in the amount of deposits created from each rupee in reserve. This is counter-intuitive. I would have expected the multiplier to stay stable or increase slightly, since theoretically digitization makes it easier to open a new account or access bank credit.
There are two possible explanations: banks could be creating less in loans/advances, and/or fewer deposits are being created. But the ratios of net advances to assets and deposits to liabilities have not changed substantially during that period of time. The only explanation that remains is that the growth of banks’ balance sheets, and the financial sector broadly, has slowed down.
While this is consistent with the broader lack of financial penetration in Pakistan, I have not found an explanation for why the money multiplier has decreased. Some incomplete explanations could include the increasing allure of real estate and other assets as a substitute for deposits, the increase in anti-money laundering and know-your-customer regulations related to opening deposit accounts, or illegal capital flight.
Or perhaps the decrease in the multiplier reflects a broader secular trend that we have yet to understand. But it may be substantial for a digital bank, especially if this has to do with consumer behavior and preferences for other assets over any bank deposit.
Data from SBP Handbook, Section 4
= 1700 * (1-15%) * 8% - 1700 * 3.4%